Play all audios:
Over the course of the 20th century, capitalism preserved its momentum by molding the ordinary person into a consumer with an unquenchable thirst for more stuff. By: Kerryn Higgs Listen to
this article Brought to you by Curio, an MIT Press partner The notion of human beings as consumers first took shape before World War I, but became commonplace in America in the 1920s.
Consumption is now frequently seen as our principal role in the world. People, of course, have always “consumed” the necessities of life — food, shelter, clothing — and have always had to
work to get them or have others work for them, but there was little economic motive for increased consumption among the mass of people before the 20th century. Quite the reverse: Frugality
and thrift were more appropriate to situations where survival rations were not guaranteed. Attempts to promote new fashions, harness the “propulsive power of envy,” and boost sales
multiplied in Britain in the late 18th century. Here began the “slow unleashing of the acquisitive instincts,” write historians Neil McKendrick, John Brewer, and J.H. Plumb in their
influential book on the commercialization of 18th-century England, when the pursuit of opulence and display first extended beyond the very rich. But, while poorer people might have acquired
a very few useful household items — a skillet, perhaps, or an iron pot — the sumptuous clothing, furniture, and pottery of the era were still confined to a very small population. In late
19th-century Britain a variety of foods became accessible to the average person, who would previously have lived on bread and potatoes — consumption beyond mere subsistence. This improvement
in food variety did not extend durable items to the mass of people, however. The proliferating shops and department stores of that period served only a restricted population of urban
middle-class people in Europe, but the display of tempting products in shops in daily public view was greatly extended — and display was a key element in the fostering of fashion and envy.
Although the period after World War II is often identified as the beginning of the immense eruption of consumption across the industrialized world, the historian William Leach locates its
roots in the United States around the turn of the century. In the United States, existing shops were rapidly extended through the 1890s, mail-order shopping surged, and the new century saw
massive multistory department stores covering millions of acres of selling space. Retailing was already passing decisively from small shopkeepers to corporate giants who had access to
investment bankers and drew on assembly-line production of commodities, powered by fossil fuels; the traditional objective of making products for their self-evident usefulness was displaced
by the goal of profit and the need for a machinery of enticement. “The cardinal features of this culture were acquisition and consumption as the means of achieving happiness; the cult of the
new; the democratization of desire; and money value as the predominant measure of all value in society,” Leach writes in his 1993 book “Land of Desire: Merchants, Power, and the Rise of a
New American Culture.” Significantly, it was individual desire that was democratized, rather than wealth or political and economic power. THE 1920S: “THE NEW ECONOMIC GOSPEL OF CONSUMPTION”
Release from the perils of famine and premature starvation was in place for most people in the industrialized world soon after the Great War ended. U.S. production was more than 12 times
greater in 1920 than in 1860, while the population over the same period had increased by only a factor of three, suggesting just how much additional wealth was theoretically available. The
labor struggles of the 19th century had, without jeopardizing the burgeoning productivity, gradually eroded the seven-day week of 14- and 16-hour days that was worked at the beginning of the
Industrial Revolution in England. In the United States in particular, economic growth had succeeded in providing basic security to the great majority of an entire population. In these
circumstances, there was a social choice to be made. A steady-state economy capable of meeting the basic needs of all, foreshadowed by philosopher and political economist John Stuart Mill as
the _stationary state_, seemed well within reach and, in Mill’s words, likely to be an improvement on “the trampling, crushing, elbowing and treading on each other’s heels … the
disagreeable symptoms of one of the phases of industrial progress.” It would be feasible to reduce hours of work further and release workers for the spiritual and pleasurable activities of
free time with families and communities, and creative or educational pursuits. But business did not support such a trajectory, and it was not until the Great Depression that hours were
reduced, in response to overwhelming levels of unemployment. In 1930 the U.S. cereal manufacturer Kellogg adopted a six-hour shift to help accommodate unemployed workers, and other forms of
work-sharing became more widespread. Although the shorter workweek appealed to Kellogg’s workers, the company, after reverting to longer hours during World War II, was reluctant to renew the
six-hour shift in 1945. Workers voted for it by three-to-one in both 1945 and 1946, suggesting that, at the time, they still found life in their communities more attractive than consumer
goods. This was particularly true of women. Kellogg, however, gradually overcame the resistance of its workers and whittled away at the short shifts until the last of them were abolished in
1985. Even if a shorter working day became an acceptable strategy during the Great Depression, the economic system’s orientation toward profit and its bias toward growth made such a
trajectory unpalatable to most captains of industry and the economists who theorized their successes. If profit and growth were lagging, the system needed new impetus. The short depression
of 1921–1922 led businessmen and economists in the United States to fear that the immense productive powers created over the previous century had grown sufficiently to meet the basic needs
of the entire population and had probably triggered a permanent crisis of overproduction; prospects for further economic expansion were thought to look bleak. The historian Benjamin
Hunnicutt, who examined the mainstream press of the 1920s, along with the publications of corporations, business organizations, and government inquiries, found extensive evidence that such
fears were widespread in business circles during the 1920s. Victor Cutter, president of the United Fruit Company, exemplified the concern when he wrote in 1927 that the greatest economic
problem of the day was the lack of “consuming power” in relation to the prodigious powers of production. Notwithstanding the panic and pessimism, a consumer solution was simultaneously
emerging. As the popular historian of the time Frederick Allen wrote, “Business had learned as never before the importance of the ultimate consumer. Unless he could be persuaded to buy and
buy lavishly, the whole stream of six-cylinder cars, super heterodynes, cigarettes, rouge compacts and electric ice boxes would be dammed up at its outlets.” In his classic 1928 book
“Propaganda,” Edward Bernays, one of the pioneers of the public relations industry, put it this way: > Mass production is profitable only if its rhythm can be > maintained—that is if
it can continue to sell its product in > steady or increasing quantity.… Today supply must actively seek to > create its corresponding demand … [and] cannot afford to wait > until
the public asks for its product; it must maintain constant > touch, through advertising and propaganda … to assure itself the > continuous demand which alone will make its costly plant
profitable. Edward Cowdrick, an economist who advised corporations on their management and industrial relations policies, called it “the new economic gospel of consumption,” in which
workers (people for whom durable possessions had rarely been a possibility) could be educated in the new “skills of consumption.” It was an idea also put forward by the new “consumption
economists” such as Hazel Kyrk and Theresa McMahon, and eagerly embraced by many business leaders. New needs would be created, with advertising brought into play to “augment and accelerate”
the process. People would be encouraged to give up thrift and husbandry, to value goods over free time. Kyrk argued for ever-increasing aspirations: “a high standard of living must be
dynamic, a progressive standard,” where envy of those just above oneself in the social order incited consumption and fueled economic growth. President Herbert Hoover’s 1929 Committee on
Recent Economic Changes welcomed the demonstration “on a grand scale [of] the expansibility of human wants and desires,” hailed an “almost insatiable appetite for goods and services,” and
envisaged “a boundless field before us … new wants that make way endlessly for newer wants, as fast as they are satisfied.” In this paradigm, people are encouraged to board an escalator of
desires (a stairway to heaven, perhaps) and progressively ascend to what were once the luxuries of the affluent. Charles Kettering, general director of General Motors Research Laboratories,
equated such perpetual change with progress. In a 1929 article called “Keep the Consumer Dissatisfied,” he stated that “there is no place anyone can sit and rest in an industrial situation.
It is a question of change, change all the time — and it is always going to be that way because the world only goes along one road, the road of progress.” These views parallel political
economist Joseph Schumpeter’s later characterization of capitalism as “creative destruction”: > Capitalism, then, is by nature a form or method of economic change > and not only never
is, but _never can be stationary_.… The > fundamental impulse that sets and keeps the capitalist engine in > motion comes from the new consumers, goods, the new methods of >
production or transportation, the new markets, the new forms of > industrial organization that capitalist enterprise creates. The prospect of ever-extendable consumer desire,
characterized as “progress,” promised a new way forward for modern manufacture, a means to perpetuate economic growth. Progress was about the endless replacement of old needs with new, old
products with new. Notions of meeting everyone’s needs with an adequate level of production did not feature. The nonsettler European colonies were not regarded as viable venues for these new
markets, since centuries of exploitation and impoverishment meant that few people there were able to pay. In the 1920s, the target consumer market to be nourished lay at home in the
industrialized world. There, especially in the United States, consumption continued to expand through the 1920s, though truncated by the Great Depression of 1929. Electrification was crucial
for the consumption of the new types of durable items, and the fraction of U.S. households with electricity connected nearly doubled between 1921 and 1929, from 35 percent to 68 percent; a
rapid proliferation of radios, vacuum cleaners, and refrigerators followed. Motor car registration rose from eight million in 1920 to more than 28 million by 1929. The introduction of time
payment arrangements facilitated the extension of such buying further and further down the economic ladder. In Australia, too, the trend could be observed; there, however, the base was tiny,
and even though car ownership multiplied nearly fivefold in the eight years to 1929, few working-class households possessed cars or large appliances before 1945. This first wave of
consumerism was short-lived. Predicated on debt, it took place in an economy mired in speculation and risky borrowing. U.S. consumer credit rose to $7 billion in the 1920s, with banks
engaged in reckless lending of all kinds. Indeed, though a lot less in gross terms than the burden of debt in the United States in late 2008, which Sydney economist Steve Keen has described
as “the biggest load of unsuccessful gambling in history,” the debt of the 1920s was very large, over 200 percent of the GDP of the time. In both eras, borrowed money bought unprecedented
quantities of material goods on time payment and (these days) credit cards. The 1920s bonanza collapsed suddenly and catastrophically. In 2008, a similar unraveling began; its implications
still remain unknown. In the case of the Great Depression of the 1930s, a war economy followed, so it was almost 20 years before mass consumption resumed any role in economic life — or in
the way the economy was conceived. ------------------------- THE SECOND WAVE Once World War II was over, consumer culture took off again throughout the developed world, partly fueled by the
deprivation of the Great Depression and the rationing of the wartime years and incited with renewed zeal by corporate advertisers using debt facilities and the new medium of television.
Stuart Ewen, in his history of the public relations industry, saw the birth of commercial radio in 1921 as a vital tool in the great wave of debt-financed consumption in the 1920s — “a
privately owned utility, pumping information and entertainment into people’s homes.” “Requiring no significant degree of literacy on the part of its audience,” Ewen writes, “radio gave
interested corporations … unprecedented access to the inner sanctums of the public mind.” The advent of television greatly magnified the potential impact of advertisers’ messages, exploiting
image and symbol far more adeptly than print and radio had been able to do. The stage was set for the democratization of luxury on a scale hitherto unimagined. Though the television sets
that carried the advertising into people’s homes after World War II were new, and were far more powerful vehicles of persuasion than radio had been, the theory and methods were the same —
perfected in the 1920s by PR experts like Bernays. Vance Packard echoes both Bernays and the consumption economists of the 1920s in his description of the role of the advertising men of the
1950s: > They want to put some sizzle into their messages by stirring up our > status consciousness.… Many of the products they are trying to > sell have, in the past, been confined
to a “quality market.” The > products have been the luxuries of the upper classes. The game is to > _make them the necessities of all classes_. This is done by dangling > the
products before non-upper-class people as status symbols of a > higher class. By striving to buy the product—say, wall-to-wall > carpeting on instalment—the consumer is made to feel he
is > upgrading himself socially. Though it is status that is being sold, it is endless material objects that are being consumed. In a little-known 1958 essay reflecting on the
conservation implications of the conspicuously wasteful U.S. consumer binge after World War II, John Kenneth Galbraith pointed to the possibility that this “gargantuan and growing appetite”
might need to be curtailed. “What of the appetite itself?,” he asks. “Surely this is the ultimate source of the problem. If it continues its geometric course, will it not one day have to be
restrained? Yet in the literature of the resource problem this is the forbidden question.” Galbraith quotes the President’s Materials Policy Commission setting out its premise that economic
growth is sacrosanct. “First we share the belief of the American people in the principle of Growth,” the report maintains, specifically endorsing “ever more luxurious standards of
consumption.” To Galbraith, who had just published “The Affluent Society,” the wastefulness he observed seemed foolhardy, but he was pessimistic about curtailment; he identified the
beginnings of “a massive conservative reaction to the idea of enlarged social guidance and control of economic activity,” a backlash against the state taking responsibility for social
direction. At the same time he was well aware of the role of advertising: “Goods are plentiful. Demand for them must be elaborately contrived,” he wrote. “Those who create wants rank amongst
our most talented and highly paid citizens. Want creation — advertising — is a ten billion dollar industry.” Or, as retail analyst Victor Lebow remarked in 1955: > Our enormously
productive economy demands that we make consumption > our way of life, that we convert the buying and use of goods into > rituals, that we seek our spiritual satisfaction, our ego >
satisfaction, in consumption.… We need things consumed, burned up, > replaced and discarded at an ever-accelerating rate. Thus, just as immense effort was being devoted to persuading
people to buy things they did not actually need, manufacturers also began the intentional design of inferior items, which came to be known as “planned obsolescence.” In his second major
critique of the culture of consumption, “The Waste Makers,” Packard identified both functional obsolescence, in which the product wears out quickly and psychological obsolescence, in which
products are “designed to become obsolete in the mind of the consumer, even sooner than the components used to make them will fail.” Galbraith was alert to the way that rapidly expanding
consumption patterns were multiplied by a rapidly expanding population. But postwar industrial enterprise stoked the expansion nonetheless. The rise of consumer debt, interrupted in 1929,
also resumed. In Australia, the 1939 debt of AU$39 million doubled in the first two years after the war and, by 1960, had grown by a factor of 25, to more than AU$1 billion dollars. This new
burst in debt-financed consumerism was, again, incited intentionally. TAPPING INTO THE UNCONSCIOUS: IMAGE AND MESSAGE In researching his excellent history of the rise of PR, Ewen
interviewed Bernays himself in 1990, not long before he turned 99. Ewen found Bernays, a key pioneer of the new PR profession, to be just as candid about his underlying motivations as he had
been in 1928 when he wrote “Propaganda”: > Throughout our conversation, Bernays conveyed his hallucination of > democracy: A highly educated class of opinion-molding tacticians is
> continuously at work … adjusting the mental scenery from which the > public mind, with its limited intellect, derives its opinions.… > Throughout the interview, he described PR as
a response to a > transhistoric concern: the requirement, for those people in power, > to shape the attitudes of the general population. Bernays’s views, like those of several other
analysts of the “crowd” and the “herd instinct,” were a product of the panic created among the elite classes by the early 20th-century transition from the limited franchise of propertied men
to universal suffrage. “On every side of American life, whether political, industrial, social, religious or scientific, the increasing pressure of public judgment has made itself felt,”
Bernays wrote. “The great corporation which is in danger of having its profits taxed away or its sales fall off or its freedom impeded by legislative action must have recourse to the public
to combat successfully these menaces.” The opening page of “Propaganda” discloses his solution: > The conscious and intelligent manipulation of the organized habits > and opinions of
the masses is an important element in democratic > society. Those who manipulate this unseen mechanism of society > constitute an invisible government which is the true ruling power of
> our country.… It is they who pull the wires which control the > public mind, who harness old social forces and contrive new ways to > bind and guide the world. The front-line
thinkers of the emerging advertising and public relations industries turned to the key insights of Sigmund Freud, Bernays’s uncle. As Bernays noted: > Many of man’s thoughts and actions
are compensatory substitutes > for desires which [he] has been obliged to suppress. A thing may be > desired, not for its intrinsic worth or usefulness, but because he > has
unconsciously come to see in it a symbol of something else, the > desire for which he is ashamed to admit to himself … because it is > a symbol of social position, an evidence of his
success. Bernays saw himself as a “propaganda specialist,” a “public relations counsel,” and PR as a more sophisticated craft than advertising as such; it was directed at hidden desires and
subconscious urges of which its targets would be unaware. Bernays and his colleagues were anxious to offer their services to corporations and were instrumental in founding an entire industry
that has since operated along these lines, selling not only corporate commodities but also opinions on a great range of social, political, economic, and environmental issues. Though it has
become fashionable in recent decades to brand scholars and academics as elites who pour scorn on ordinary people, Bernays and the sociologist Gustave Le Bon were long ago arguing, on behalf
of business and political elites, respectively, that the mass of people are incapable of thought. According to Le Bon, “A crowd thinks in images, and the image itself immediately calls up a
series of other images, having no logical connection with the first”; crowds “can only comprehend rough-and-ready associations of ideas,” leading to “the utter powerlessness of reasoning
when it has to fight against sentiment.” Bernays and his PR colleagues believed ordinary people to be incapable of logical thought, let alone mastery of “abstruse economic, political and
ethical data,” and saw the need to “control and regiment the masses according to our will without their knowing about it”; PR could thus ensure the maintenance of order and corporate control
in society. The commodification of reality and the manufacture of demand have had serious implications for the construction of human beings in the late 20th century, where, to quote
philosopher Herbert Marcuse, “people recognize themselves in their commodities.” Marcuse’s critique of needs, made more than 50 years ago, was not directed at the issues of scarce resources
or ecological waste, although he was aware even at that time that Marx was insufficiently critical of the continuum of progress and that there needed to be “a restoration of nature after the
horrors of capitalist industrialisation have been done away with.” Marcuse directed his critique at the way people, in the act of satisfying our aspirations, reproduce dependence on the
very exploitive apparatus that perpetuates our servitude. Hours of work in the United States have been growing since 1950, along with a doubling of consumption per capita between 1950 and
1990. Marcuse suggested that this “voluntary servitude (voluntary inasmuch as it is introjected into the individual) … can be broken only through a political practice which reaches the roots
of containment and contentment in the infrastructure of man [_sic_], a political practice of methodical disengagement from and refusal of the Establishment, aiming at a radical
transvaluation of values.” The difficult challenge posed by such a transvaluation is reflected in current attitudes. The Australian comedian Wendy Harmer in her 2008 ABC TV series called
“Stuff” expressed irritation at suggestions that consumption is simply generated out of greed or lack of awareness: > I am very proud to have made a documentary about consumption that
> does not contain the usual footage of factory smokestacks, landfill > tips and bulging supermarket trolleys. Instead, it features many > happy human faces and all their wonderful
stuff! It’s a study of a > love affair as much as anything else. In the same vein, during the Q&A after a talk given by the Australian economist Clive Hamilton at the 2006 Byron Bay
Writers’ Festival, one woman spoke up about her partner’s priorities: Rather than entertain questions about any impact his possessions might be having on the environment, she said, he was
determined to “go down with his gadgets.” The capitalist system, dependent on a logic of never-ending growth from its earliest inception, confronted the plenty it created in its home states,
especially the United States, as a threat to its very existence. It would not do if people were content because they felt they had enough. However over the course of the 20th century,
capitalism preserved its momentum by molding the ordinary person into a consumer with an unquenchable thirst for its “wonderful stuff.” ------------------------- _KERRYN HIGGS is an
Australian writer and historian. She is the author of “Collision Course: Endless Growth on a Finite Planet,” from which this article is adapted._