Play all audios:
At the end of this month, the Federal Reserve will decide once again what to do about interest rates. Virtually everyone thinks it will cut. But while the expectation is nearly unanimous, it
certainly isn't uncontroversial. Speaking for many mainstream analysts, Mohamed A. El-Erian, a former economic adviser to President Obama, pointed out that an interest rate cut will
come with real trade-offs: It will leave the central bank less prepared for the next recession, or possibly exacerbate the next financial bubble. That does not mean the Fed shouldn't
cut. It does mean the Fed is stuck in a policy prison where it has very little room to maneuver, and where none of its options are great. There are two reasons for this: The first is
Congress' failure to act on fiscal policy. The legislative branch has become so hopelessly deadlocked by Republican indifference and obstruction that action in any situation short of a
total emergency is a pipe dream. But beneath that failure is the whole way U.S. policymakers conceive of the divide between the "fiscal" and "monetary" tool kits at their
disposal. SUBSCRIBE TO THE WEEK Escape your echo chamber. Get the facts behind the news, plus analysis from multiple perspectives. SUBSCRIBE & SAVE SIGN UP FOR THE WEEK'S FREE
NEWSLETTERS From our morning news briefing to a weekly Good News Newsletter, get the best of The Week delivered directly to your inbox. From our morning news briefing to a weekly Good News
Newsletter, get the best of The Week delivered directly to your inbox. As a refresher, fiscal policy is what Congress does: taxes and spending and public investment and all that. (It can
also be what state legislatures do with those same tools.) Monetary policy is what the Federal Reserve does: buying and selling financial assets to adjust various interest rates and keep the
overall financial system from seizing up. According to the conventional Washington wisdom of recent decades, fiscal policy's job is to provide various public needs, yes, but also to
keep its own books balanced. Monetary policy's job is to balance the economy: To make sure job and wage growth is running as hot as possible, without tipping into
"overheating" and an unsustainable rise in the inflation rate. Unfortunately for the Fed, we've reached the tail end of a multi-decade experiment in this division and
assignment of roles, only to discover it doesn't work. For a start, the Fed's powers are asymmetric. It can hike interest rates — squashing job and wage growth — as much as it
wants. But it can't cut interest rates — and thus boost job and wage growth — below zero. This leads to El-Erian’s first concern: The Fed has historically needed to cut interest rates
by 4 or 5 percentage points to combat recessions. But it's currently setting them at 2.25 to 2.5 percent. That's already too low, and if the Fed starts cutting now, it will have
even less room to maneuver when the next downturn comes. Beyond that, the economy is a feedback loop between consumption and investment, and the Fed is only able to affect one side of that
feedback loop. Think of interest rates as a wall between people who want credit and people who supply credit; the Fed lowers or raises that well depending on how hot it wants the economy to
run. What the Fed can't do is create more demand for credit than is already there. If the hunger out in the economy for more credit and investment is already low, then it won't
really matter how much the Fed lowers its wall. And if the wall is already torn down, there's nowhere left to go in the case of a recession. That's basically the trap the Federal
Reserve is in. The tool that can create more demand for credit is fiscal policy. By pumping more money into people's pockets, either through welfare state spending or direct government
hiring, the government injects more aggregate demand into the economy. That gives everyday people more ability to buy goods and services, which justifies business expansions and the
credit-creation needed to fuel that investment. Unfortunately, Congress has completely dropped the ball on this front. Its fiscal stimulus in the immediate aftermath of the Great Recession
was far too small, and its done next to nothing since. The 2017 tax cut barely made a dent because nearly all its benefits went to the wealthiest, who do not need — and thus will not spend —
the additional dollars. In fact, fiscal policy has arguably under-powered the economy ever since the end of the 1970s: With every recession since, the Fed has cut interest rates lower,
without ever being able to return them to their previous high. With the Great Recession, the central bank's interest rate target finally bottomed out at zero. Fiscal policy can also
work the other way. When inflation spiked at the beginning of the 1980s, Congress could have raised taxes or tried other regulatory efforts to slow down prices while putting most of the
burden on the wealthy. Instead, we went the monetary policy route and the Fed chairman at the time, Paul Volcker, massively hiked interest rates, destroying millions of jobs and incomes in
the process and setting the country on a path toward runaway inequality. Once the downward spiral set in, only fiscal stimulus could reverse it. This ties into another one of El-Erian's
concerns today: That economic fundamentals — like business investment and wage growth — remain mediocre, despite the recovery, while stock and financial markets continue to boom — with all
their attendant risks of bubbles and busts. Frankly, policymakers shouldn't rely on interest rates to contain financial bubbles in the first place. That's a job much better suited
to regulatory oversight. But if you want higher interest rates — either to ward off irrational exuberance in the financial markets or prepare for the next recession — you need economic
fundamentals that are strong enough to support high interest rates. And that means more aggressive fiscal stimulus. Now, the Fed might be able to escape this trap if it was willing to get
really creative. At a recent hearing, Rep. Rashida Tlaib (D-Mich.) asked Fed Chairman Jerome Powell why the central bank couldn't have backstopped short-term borrowing by state
governments the same way it backstopped short-term borrowing by corporations in the aftermath of 2008. That would've allowed states to keep borrowing and spending, and thus boost the
recovery, rather than cutting their budgets and thus worsening the downturn. Powell claimed the Fed doesn't have the legal authority, which is wrong. A more honest answer is that
backstopping borrowing by government actors, as opposed to private ones, comes too close to breaching the fiscal-monetary policy divide for comfort. For now, the central bank remains too
institutionally cautious to go there. Thus, the Fed is stuck. Yes, an interest rate cut might signal undo subservience to both President Trump and Wall Street investors. But ultimately the
Fed answers to neither. Its obligation is to its legal charter, which obligates it to prioritize job growth as much as price stability. All it can do is cut rates now, and pray the economy
recovers enough to justify higher rates before the next recession. The rest is up to Congress. Explore More Analysis